Financial incentives and the health workforce
Anthony Scott A D and Luke B. Connelly B CA The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, and School of Population Health, Level 6, Alan Gilbert Building, 161 Barry Street, Melbourne, VIC 3010, Australia.
B The University of Melbourne, Australian Health Workforce Institute (AHWI), Level 3, 766 Elizabeth Street, Parkville, VIC 3010, Australia.
C The University of Queensland, Australian Centre for Economic Research on Health (ACERH) and Centre of National Research on Disability and Rehabilitation Medicine (CONROD), Ground Floor, Edith Cavell Building, Royal Brisbane and Women’s Hospital, Herston, QLD 4029, Australia.
D Corresponding author. Email: a.scott@unimelb.edu.au
Australian Health Review 35(3) 273-277 https://doi.org/10.1071/AH10904
Submitted: 29 March 2010 Accepted: 4 January 2011 Published: 25 August 2011
Journal Compilation © AHHA 2011
Abstract
Changes to the remuneration of medical practitioners are currently being considered in Australia. In this paper, we provide a discussion of financial incentives in healthcare markets and their effects on health professionals’ behaviour. After defining incentives, the paper focuses on the design of incentive schemes for the health workforce. It discusses several issues that should be considered when designing incentives, illustrated with some Australian examples. What are the objectives of the incentive scheme? What types of incentives can be used and under what circumstances? What is the empirical evidence around the effects of incentive schemes? What unintended consequences might exist? The paper concludes with a set of principles around which incentives can be designed. These principles might be used to inform the current debate about revisions to the incentives that are faced by medical practitioners in Australia.
References
[1] Cresswell A. Performance pay likely for doctors. The Australian, 6 May 2009: 4. Available at http://www.theaustralian.com.au/news/nation/performance-pay-likely-for-doctors/story-e6frg6nf-1225710305729 [verified 13 July 2011].[2] A healthier future for all Australians – final report. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia, National Health and Hospitals Reform Commission; 2009.
[3] Building a 21st century primary health care system: a draft of Australia’s first national primary health care strategy. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia, Department of Health and Ageing; 2009.
[4] Taking preventative action. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia, National Preventative Health Taskforce; 2010.
[5] Le Grand J. Motivation, Agency and Public Policy: of Knights and Knaves, Pawns and Queens. New York: Oxford University Press; 2003.
[6] Gravelle H, Sutton M, Ma A. Doctor behaviour under a pay for performance contract: further evidence from the quality and outcomes framework. CHE Research Paper 34. York, UK: Centre for Health Economics, University of York; 2008.
[7] Nicholson S, Pauly MV, Jung Wu AY, Murray JF, Teutsch SM, Berger ML. Getting real performance out of pay for performance. Milbank Q 2008; 86 435–57.
| Getting real performance out of pay for performance.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar |
[8] Cutler DM, Zeckhauser RJ. The anatomy of health insurance. In: Culyer AJ and Newhouse JP, editors. Handbook of Health Economics. Vol.1A. Amsterdam: Elsevier; 2000: 563–644.
[9] Prendergast C. The provision of incentives in firms. J Econ Lit 1999; 37 7–63.
| The provision of incentives in firms.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar |
[10] Ikenwilo D, Scott A. The effect of pay and job satisfaction on the labour supply of hospital consultants. Health Econ 2007; 16 1303–18.
| The effect of pay and job satisfaction on the labour supply of hospital consultants.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar |
[11] Baltagi B, Bratberg E, Holmes TA. panel data study of physician’s labor supply: the case of Norway. Health Econ 2005; 14 1035–45.
| panel data study of physician’s labor supply: the case of Norway.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar |
[12] Connelly LB, Butler JRG. Incentives and primary care: an analysis of the Australian Medicare arrangements and producer behaviour. ACERH; 2005. Available at http://www.acerh.edu.au/News/Butler_ResearchForum_160606.pdf [verified 5 August 2011].
[13] Gosden T, Forland F, Kristiansen IS, Sutton M, Leese B, Guiffrida A, et al Impact of payment method on the behaviour of primary care doctors: a systematic review. J Health Serv Res Policy 2001; 6 44–55.
| Impact of payment method on the behaviour of primary care doctors: a systematic review.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar | 1:STN:280:DC%2BD3M7kt1Knug%3D%3D&md5=4914cb509d85fbfb5fb42210954dcd06CAS |
[14] Gosden T, Pedersen L, Torgerson D. How should we pay doctors? A systematic review of salary payments and their effect on doctor behaviour. QJM 1999; 92 47–55.
| 1:STN:280:DyaK1M3is1WntQ%3D%3D&md5=1c2c9cd257a7411a6e72dc7964dc6b1aCAS |
[15] Robinson JC. Theory and practice in the design of physician payment incentives. Milbank Q 2001; 79 149–77.
| Theory and practice in the design of physician payment incentives.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar | 1:STN:280:DC%2BD3Mzos1Wquw%3D%3D&md5=306d1ccff2cb3e982afd24a4a94b0b30CAS |
[16] Petersen LA, Woodard LD, Urech T, Daw C, Sookanan S. Does pay-for-performance improve the quality of health care? Ann Intern Med 2006; 145 265–72.
[17] Scott IA. Pay for performance in health care: strategic issues for Australian experiments. Med J Aust 2007; 187 31–5.
[18] Mavromaras K, Scott A. Promotion to hospital consultant: regression analysis using NHS administrative data. BMJ 2006; 332 148–51.
| Promotion to hospital consultant: regression analysis using NHS administrative data.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar |
[19] Eggelston K. Multitasking and mixed systems for provider payment. J Health Econ 2005; 24 211–23.
[20] Scott A, Schurer S, Jensen PH, Sivey P. The effects of financial incentives on quality of care: the case of diabetes. Working Paper No. 12/08. Melbourne: Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research; 2008.
[21] Clarkson JE, Turner S, Grimshaw JM, Ramsay CR, Johnston M, Scott A, et al Changing clinicians’ behavior: a randomized controlled trial of fees and education. J Dent Res 2008; 87 640–4.
| Changing clinicians’ behavior: a randomized controlled trial of fees and education.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar | 1:STN:280:DC%2BD1cvgsFSnsQ%3D%3D&md5=cff1e7eddb0a8fc3ceaa48b0f17b7026CAS |
[22] Doran T, Fullwood C, Reeves D, Gravelle H, Roland M. Exclusion of patients from pay-for-performance targets by English physicians. N Engl J Med 2008; 359 274–84.
| Exclusion of patients from pay-for-performance targets by English physicians.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar | 1:CAS:528:DC%2BD1cXoslGjtLo%3D&md5=3889a8c97cc987d60464b22e8684ca3bCAS |
[23] Goddard M, Mannion R, Smith P. Enhancing performance in health care: a theoretical perspective on agency and the role of information. Health Econ 2000; 9 95–107.
| Enhancing performance in health care: a theoretical perspective on agency and the role of information.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar | 1:STN:280:DC%2BD3c7oslehsg%3D%3D&md5=4a9f3d4a39a26a3034295022aa811d08CAS |
[24] Frey BS, Jegen R. Motivation crowding theory: a survey of empirical evidence. J Econ Surv 2001; 15 589–611.
| Motivation crowding theory: a survey of empirical evidence.Crossref | GoogleScholarGoogle Scholar |